Cambridge Journals Online

Cambridge Journals Online
Canadian Journal of Political Science (2009), 42: 1057-1058 Cambridge University Press
Copyright © Canadian Political Science Association 2009
doi:10.1017/S0008423909990606 (About doi)
Published online by Cambridge University Press 14 Dec 2009
*This article is available in a PDF that may contain more than one articles.
Therefore the PDF file's first page may not match this article's first page.
Canadian Journal of Political Science (2009), 42:1057-1058 Cambridge University Press
Copyright © Canadian Political Science Association 2009
doi:10.1017/S0008423909990606

Reviews / Recensions

Capital as Power: A Study of Order and Creorder, Jonathan Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler, New York: Routledge, 2009, pp. xxvi, 438.

  Book query
  Google Scholar

Jordan Brennana1

a1 York University
Article author query
brennan j Google Scholar

In Capital as Power Jonathan Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler address one of the oldest theoretical conundrums in the discipline of political economy—the theory of capital—with a view to supplying a more satisfactory answer to the question “what is capital?” While the work clearly fits into the tradition of radical political economy it is not easy to place it in any one school, and this for very good reason: Nitzan and Bichler are trying to create a new approach to political economy. The release of this highly ambitious book is aptly timed, for as the global political–economic crisis unfolds and existing theories and paradigms come into question, a space will be created in which new theoretical alternatives might be welcomed.

One way of classifying approaches to political economy is through theories of value. A theory of value is a metaphysical assumption about how prices are formed. Both neoclassical and Marxist approaches have a theory of capital and price formation that are derived from a utility and labour theory of value respectively. However, Nitzan and Bichler claim that both theories of value fail. They cannot explain what capital is, how and why it accumulates, what gets accumulated and, similarly, how prices are formed and why they fluctuate over time. In place of neoclassical marginal utility and Marxist abstract labour Nitzan and Bichler propose a power theory of value.

For the authors, “the secret to understanding [capital] accumulation … lies not in the narrow confines of production and consumption, but in the broader processes and institutions of power,” the implication being that capital is not an economic category anchored in material reality, as both mainstream and radical theories maintain, rather it is a “symbolic representation of power” (7). “Power” in the sense they employ it does not mean “economic power” or “political power” but “organized power at large” (9). Most political scientists will likely find this problematic. Academic departmentalization and liberal ideology have tended to divide the study of society into separate, though overlapping systems. The “economic” system is different than the “political” in that markets and business are institutionally separate from the state and government. Each system operates according to its own logic, pursues different goals, utilizes different means, has its own discourse, and so on. In order to follow their argument, however, we must suspend this bit of conventional disciplinary wisdom.

They insist that instead of thinking of accumulation in absolute terms we should think of it in differential terms, and instead of approaching the business sector as a whole or capital in general we should focus on the largest firms at the centre of the political economy, what they call “dominant capital.” With these two operative concepts—dominant capital and differential accumulation—Nitzan and Bichler measure and map the quantitative patterns of capitalist development in the United States over the previous century with astonishing results. A key assumption in this approach is that “capital accumulation and the changing power of capitalists are one and the same” and since we can only understand force through its effects, capital only comes to have meaning by contrasting “the quantitative patterns of differential accumulation … with the qualitative power institutions, organizations and process that underlie this accumulation” (312–13). This is a broad and highly speculative understanding to be sure, but their metaphysical premises yield precise categories for understanding accumulation. According to their framework, “differential accumulation is … an ongoing struggle to restructure society against opposition. The form of the process is the quantitative redistribution of ownership, its content the qualitative transformation of power relations” (325). As the subtitle indicates, to create order or “creorder” is the ability to impose order against opposition and this ever-present tension between force and counterforce means that change is institutionalized under capitalism. The architecture of prices, then, is the quantitative manifestation of this change and reflects a qualitative power process in which absentee owners (“investors”) engage in a distributional struggle over corporate ownership claims and their associated streams of expected future earnings.

Some will likely find their claims outlandish to the point of being conspiratorial while others might see it as a highly innovative paradigm shift in the study of society. At the centre of their analysis, acting as a lodestar, is “power,” a highly amorphous concept and one likely to be questioned by heterodox and orthodox readers alike. What cannot be called into question is the seriousness, scope or ambition of this work. Characteristic of their style, the authors combine deep historical perspective with a highly interdisciplinary approach to the study of society, as evidenced by references to figures as diverse as Galileo, Newton, Lavoisier, Orwell, Koestler and Marquez. Nor will the reader fail to be impressed by their quantitative work and their imaginative formation of concepts, which often find stunning empirical confirmation.

Though highly original and inventive in their thinking, Nitzan and Bichler have plenty of debts to pay. They rely heavily upon the work of Karl Marx, Thorstein Veblen and Lewis Mumford, to name a few. The book is geared towards heterodox political economists of all sorts, students of political economy and those outside the academy who are willing to engage with their work. For a subject that can often be heavily jargon laden, Nitzan and Bichler do a remarkable job of keeping their explanations and examples simple and clear. This book is attempting to be paradigmatic and even if it fails in this endeavour it is likely to cause a stir.


back to top
Cambridge University Press